Key Takeaways
- The European Central Bank's (ECB's) effective policy rate could reach 1.5% as early as the end of 2023, with the first 25 basis point (bp) hike in all three policy rates scheduled for July 2022, and the second for September 2022, possibly at a larger increment.
- Balance sheet unwinding will take more time, as the ECB has not yet committed to ending reinvestments of maturing securities held under quantitative easing (QE).
- That said, the ECB's decision on the future of its targeted longer-term refinancing operations (TLTROs) will also affect the pace and scope of the balance sheet unwinding.
- Bond market conditions have tightened, but the effect of the ECB's balance sheet expansion on the term premium will likely continue to depress long-term yields by around 90 bps until balance sheet unwinding starts.
Significant increases in energy and food prices are likely to keep inflation above the ECB's target of 2% over the next two years. Eurozone inflation expectations over the next five years are also above 2%. With high inflation starting to dampen household consumption and growth, the ECB has clearly indicated that the time has come to normalize monetary policy. As the ECB's president, Christine Lagarde, stated in a recent blog post, not adjusting policy rates in this environment would amount to unnecessary policy easing. GDP growth in the eurozone of 0.6% in the first quarter of 2022 versus the prior quarter, a strong upward revision of the original estimate, supports the ECB's view.
The ECB reiterated its intention to normalize policy in today's meeting, announcing the end of both preferential rates on TLTROs and net asset purchases, alongside the hikes in all three policy rates in July and September 2022. The ECB has added several tools to its arsenal since the last normalization cycle prior to the financial crisis of 2007-2008. Normalization therefore not only means increasing interest rates, but also phasing out unconventional tools such as QE and TLTROs.
The Effective Policy Rate Will Reach 1.5% In Late 2023
The ECB intends to raise the three policy rates by 25 bps in July, and again in September, possibly at a larger increment depending on the new inflation forecasts at the time. Beyond September, we expect the ECB to continue raising rates in 25 bp increments on a quarterly basis until its effective policy rate reaches 1.5%, which is what we understand the ECB's current estimate of the neutral rate to be. In a speech at the beginning of May 2022, the governor of the French central bank, Villeroy de Galhau, put real neutral rates between -1% and 0% in the euro area, echoing previous estimates by ECB board member Isabel Schnabel at the end of 2021 (see "Related Research").
We expect the neutral rate to be the terminal rate for this cycle, since the output gap is unlikely to become strongly positive in the coming two years and inflation should recede from its current level. Under our baseline assumptions, we think that the rate-hiking cycle could end as soon as the final quarter of 2023. That said, the actual pace at which the policy rate rises to neutral will ultimately depend on the data. What's more, although the neutral rate is subject to slow-moving dynamics--that is, demographics, productivity cycles, the return on capital, and the demand for safe assets--the ECB may change its estimates of the neutral rate as its tightening cycle progresses if it sees any of these factors changing in the post-pandemic world.
For now, the ECB's de facto policy rate will continue to be the deposit rate as long as excess liquidity remains in the system (see chart 1). Banks have accumulated abundant liquidity over the past decade because of the ECB's credit easing (TLTROs) and asset purchases. This, and the full allotment procedure--banks' ability to satisfy all their bids for liquidity at the central banks--mean that they have made little use of the interbank market in past years. Furthermore, as long as banks keep large amounts of excess reserves, the euro short-term market rate is likely to continue tracking the deposit rate.
It is unclear what level of excess liquidity would bring the interbank market, and thus the refinancing rate, back into play. According to its Financial Stability Review from May 2022, the ECB expects that banks will repay €700 billion of TLTROs by year-end 2022. However, a quick back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that it would take excess liquidity dropping at least below €1 trillion for the euro short-term market rate to move closer to the refinancing rate (see chart 2). Whether or not excess liquidity will fall as low as this threshold will also depend on market and bank lending conditions in an environment of rising short-term interest rates. The ECB might be tempted to inject long-term liquidity into the system in the event of an unwarranted tightening of financing conditions. Therefore, it could take time for the rate instruments to normalize fully, and the ECB could maintain its floor policy rate framework throughout this rate-tightening cycle.
Chart 1
Chart 2
The ECB's Balance Sheet Is Likely To Remain Large, Even As Interest Rates Rise
The ECB's balance sheet has expanded by up by €6.6 trillion since 2015. One-quarter of this, €1.7 trillion, came from the ECB increasing the TLTROs it granted to banks, and three-quarters, €4.7 trillion, came from outright purchases of securities (see chart 3). The ECB could normalize the size of its balance sheet with the same two instruments, but the pace of the endeavor, and the extent to which it would reduce each instrument, remain unclear.
Chart 3
The end of preferential rates on TLTROs
The ECB's announcement of the end of the preferential interest rate for TLTROs is coherent with the start of the interest rate normalization cycle. In a higher rate environment, it wouldn't make sense for the ECB to further incentivize lending at a lower interest rate than its policy rate as it would cause the economy to overheat, something the ECB seeks to prevent. The ECB expects banks to repay some €700 billion until the end of 2022. Nevertheless, the ECB could choose to engage in another round of TLTROs in the event of an unwarranted tightening of financing conditions that risks upsetting the smooth transmission of its interest rate policy across the euro area. Flexibility, optionality, and gradualism are the ECB's stated guiding principles of its monetary policy normalization efforts.
The end of net asset purchases
While the ECB has confirmed an end to its net asset purchases as of July 1, 2022, there is still little clarity on the start and extent of the downsizing yet. So far, the ECB has committed to reinvesting maturing securities under the pandemic emergency purchase program until the end of 2024. Unlike the U.S. Federal Reserve and the Bank of England, the ECB has not yet communicated a willingness to reduce the size of its balance sheet through outright sales of bonds held under QE. Since the average maturity of the securities on its balance sheet is around seven years, it would take the ECB until at least 2030 to unwind its asset purchases by not reinvesting.
That said, the ECB could choose to reinvest maturing securities in bonds with shorter or longer maturities if it seeks more tightening or loosening in the future. Moreover, should financing conditions remain favorable, the ECB could also decide to actively sell bond purchases to unwind its balance sheet. On the other hand, should financing conditions worsen to the point of excessive fragmentation among members states, the ECB could be tempted to launch a new asset purchase facility, as several ECB members have suggested (see Christine Lagarde's blogpost "Monetary policy normalisation in the euro area"). Such options could make the normalization of the ECB's balance sheet take even longer.
Long-Term Yields Should Not Rise Much Further As The ECB Starts To Normalize Policy
Bond market conditions have become less favorable since the ECB started signaling monetary policy tightening in March 2022. For example, German ten-year yields have risen by around 140 bps since December 2021. While there is a relatively good understanding of how increases in the main policy rate affect financing, there is still little clarity on what will happen to yields when the ECB ends QE and starts to normalize its balance sheet.
Our modelling results suggest that what matters most in the depression of long-term yields is the size of the ECB's balance sheet (the stock effect), while the monthly increase in the ECB's balance sheet (the flow effect) has an insignificant impact on rates. The ECB's balance sheet expansion since 2015 has meant that the stock effect had a growing impact on yields over time, depressing 10-year bund yields by around 110 bps after one year and as much as 200 bps after four years (see chart 4). By contrast, the flow effect has had a small to insignificant effect on yields (see chart 5), suggesting that the end of net asset purchases shouldn't trigger a rise in yields.
In other words, as long as the ECB holds a large proportion of sovereign bonds on its balance sheet (currently around 40% of outstanding eurozone government bonds) and banks hold excess reserves at the ECB, this will continue to depress yields by constraining the supply available to price-sensitive investors.
Chart 4
Chart 5
The ECB's balance sheet expansion has affected both the risk-free rate and the term premium
The stock effect arises partly from investors' expectations, and not just the ECB's balance sheet holdings. As such, a large part of the effects on yields is priced in ahead or around the timing of the QE announcement. This is because the QE effect has two channels--a signaling channel and a supply scarcity channel. The signaling channel--which is largely tied to the ECB's forward guidance on interest rates--is likely priced in immediately, whereas the effects on supply (the scarcity channel) may take more time to unfold, explaining why the stock effect grows stronger over time. In the context of balance sheet unwinding, it implies that the signaling effect dissipates when rate tightening is on the cards, while the scarcity effect is likely to last longer.
To illustrate these dynamics, we disentangled the two main channels by splitting the German ten-year yield curve into a term premium--the risk premium investors pay for holding a bond with a longer maturity date, and a risk-free rate component--investors' policy rate expectations across the yield curve. The term premium shows the size of the scarcity effect, while the risk-free rate shows the effect on the signaling channel.
The results confirm that the ECB's balance sheet expansion has affected both the risk-free rate and the term premium. Specifically, it has lowered the term premium by around 90 basis points (see table 1), and has had a significant 120 bp impact on risk-free-rate expectations (see table 2). The recent rise in the risk-free rate confirms that the signaling effect has already dissipated (see chart 6), since the ECB has already communicated the end of its purchases. At the same time, the scarcity channel is still at work, with our term premium estimates still close to zero (the recent rise is mostly linked to higher inflation). Our estimates hold firm using different specifications, with three different models showing similar results. The total impact is similar to that under the SVAR model we used in charts 4 and 5. Our results are also very close to the estimates of ECB staff.
Chart 6
Chart 7
Chart 8
Table 1
Model Results--Impact Of The ECB's Balance Sheet Expansion On The Term Premium | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Term premium drivers | ||||||||
Model | 1 | 2 | 3 | |||||
100*DLOG(CPI,0,12) | 0.29 | 0.30 | 0.25 | |||||
100*DLOG(IP(-1),0,12) | (0.01) | (0.02) | ||||||
D(EONIA) | (0.12) | |||||||
EONIA | (0.15) | (0.16) | (0.16) | |||||
DLOG(ECBBS) | (0.50) | |||||||
LOG(ECBBS) | (0.75) | (0.77) | (0.76) | |||||
LOG(SMOVE) | 1.11 | 1.12 | 1.15 | |||||
LOG(ECB_STRESS) | 0.07 | |||||||
Unemployment rate | 0.22 | 0.22 | 0.20 | |||||
D(enemployment rate) | 0.72 | |||||||
Rsquared | 0.83 | 0.83 | 0.83 | |||||
ECB balance sheet expansion impact on term premium | (0.84) | (0.86) | (0.86) | |||||
All coefficients are significant at the 1% level. ECBBS--ECB balance sheet. CPI--Consumer Price Index. IP--Industrial production. SMOVE--Volatility indices. ECB_STRESS--ECB systemic stress indicator. | ||||||||
Table 2
Model Results--Impact Of The ECB's Balance Sheet Expansion On The Risk-Free Rate | |||
---|---|---|---|
Risk-free rate drivers | |||
Model | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Constant | 0.36 | 3.57 | 5.66 |
EONIA | 0.71 | 0.56 | 0.47 |
D(EONIA) | 0.27 | 0.26 | |
LOG(ECBBS) | (0.38) | (0.52) | |
DLOG(ECBBS) | (1.02) | (1.09) | |
Unemployment rate | (0.09) | ||
D(unemployment rate) | (0.27) | ||
Rsquared | 0.93 | 0.95 | 0.96 |
QE impact on risk-free yield | (1.15) | (1.22) | |
All coefficients are significant at the 1% level. ECBBS--ECB balance sheet. QE--Quantitative easing. |
Yields Should Remain Depressed Until The ECB Starts To Reduce Its Balance Sheet
The results of our models suggest that yields are likely to stay depressed for some time, even as the ECB normalizes monetary policy. As risk-free-rate expectations are already close to the neutral rate, lower yields will mostly materialize through a lower term premium of around 90 bps lower until the ECB starts to reduce the size of its balance sheet. Meanwhile, although the ECB may not be buying additional assets, eurozone governments are starting to reduce their net issuances, which means that safe-asset supply constraints are likely to remain broadly the same for investors. This suggests that the ECB's actions will keep a lid on the tightening of long-term financing conditions in the eurozone, at least until it starts to unwind its balance sheet.
Related External Research
- Financial Stability Review, ECB, May 2022
- Monetary policy normalisation in the euro area, blog post by Christine Lagarde, May 23, 2022
- The Eurosystem and its monetary policy - from an "impossible dilemma" to a possible roadmap for normalization, speech by Villeroy de Galhau, Paris, May 6, 2022
- A new strategy for a changing world, speech by Isabel Schnabel, July 14, 2021
- Eser F., Lemke W., Nyholm K., Radde S., Vladu A. (2019), Tracing the impact of ECB's asset purchase programme on the yield curve, ECB Working Paper
- Adrian, Crump and Moench (2008), Pricing the Term Structure with Linear Regressions, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No. 340
This report does not constitute a rating action.
Senior Economist: | Marion Amiot, London + 44(0)2071760128; marion.amiot@spglobal.com |
Chief Economist, EMEA: | Sylvain Broyer, Frankfurt + 49 693 399 9156; sylvain.broyer@spglobal.com |
No content (including ratings, credit-related analyses and data, valuations, model, software, or other application or output therefrom) or any part thereof (Content) may be modified, reverse engineered, reproduced, or distributed in any form by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written permission of Standard & Poor’s Financial Services LLC or its affiliates (collectively, S&P). The Content shall not be used for any unlawful or unauthorized purposes. S&P and any third-party providers, as well as their directors, officers, shareholders, employees, or agents (collectively S&P Parties) do not guarantee the accuracy, completeness, timeliness, or availability of the Content. S&P Parties are not responsible for any errors or omissions (negligent or otherwise), regardless of the cause, for the results obtained from the use of the Content, or for the security or maintenance of any data input by the user. The Content is provided on an “as is” basis. S&P PARTIES DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING, BUT NOT LIMITED TO, ANY WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE OR USE, FREEDOM FROM BUGS, SOFTWARE ERRORS OR DEFECTS, THAT THE CONTENT’S FUNCTIONING WILL BE UNINTERRUPTED, OR THAT THE CONTENT WILL OPERATE WITH ANY SOFTWARE OR HARDWARE CONFIGURATION. In no event shall S&P Parties be liable to any party for any direct, indirect, incidental, exemplary, compensatory, punitive, special or consequential damages, costs, expenses, legal fees, or losses (including, without limitation, lost income or lost profits and opportunity costs or losses caused by negligence) in connection with any use of the Content even if advised of the possibility of such damages.
Credit-related and other analyses, including ratings, and statements in the Content are statements of opinion as of the date they are expressed and not statements of fact. S&P’s opinions, analyses, and rating acknowledgment decisions (described below) are not recommendations to purchase, hold, or sell any securities or to make any investment decisions, and do not address the suitability of any security. S&P assumes no obligation to update the Content following publication in any form or format. The Content should not be relied on and is not a substitute for the skill, judgment, and experience of the user, its management, employees, advisors, and/or clients when making investment and other business decisions. S&P does not act as a fiduciary or an investment advisor except where registered as such. While S&P has obtained information from sources it believes to be reliable, S&P does not perform an audit and undertakes no duty of due diligence or independent verification of any information it receives. Rating-related publications may be published for a variety of reasons that are not necessarily dependent on action by rating committees, including, but not limited to, the publication of a periodic update on a credit rating and related analyses.
To the extent that regulatory authorities allow a rating agency to acknowledge in one jurisdiction a rating issued in another jurisdiction for certain regulatory purposes, S&P reserves the right to assign, withdraw, or suspend such acknowledgement at any time and in its sole discretion. S&P Parties disclaim any duty whatsoever arising out of the assignment, withdrawal, or suspension of an acknowledgment as well as any liability for any damage alleged to have been suffered on account thereof.
S&P keeps certain activities of its business units separate from each other in order to preserve the independence and objectivity of their respective activities. As a result, certain business units of S&P may have information that is not available to other S&P business units. S&P has established policies and procedures to maintain the confidentiality of certain nonpublic information received in connection with each analytical process.
S&P may receive compensation for its ratings and certain analyses, normally from issuers or underwriters of securities or from obligors. S&P reserves the right to disseminate its opinions and analyses. S&P's public ratings and analyses are made available on its Web sites, www.spglobal.com/ratings (free of charge), and www.ratingsdirect.com (subscription), and may be distributed through other means, including via S&P publications and third-party redistributors. Additional information about our ratings fees is available at www.spglobal.com/usratingsfees.