articles Ratings /ratings/en/research/articles/210427-next-generation-eu-will-shift-european-growth-into-a-higher-gear-11929949 content esgSubNav
In This List
COMMENTS

Next Generation EU Will Shift European Growth Into A Higher Gear

COMMENTS

Economic Research: Global Economic Outlook Q1 2025: Buckle Up

COMMENTS

Economic Outlook U.S. Q1 2025: Steady Growth, Significant Policy Uncertainty

COMMENTS

Economic Outlook Emerging Markets Q1 2025: Trade Uncertainty Threatens Growth

COMMENTS

Economic Outlook Canada Q1 2025: Immigration Policies Hamper Growth Expectations


Next Generation EU Will Shift European Growth Into A Higher Gear

With its €750 billion Next Generation plan, the EU aims to repair the damage that COVID-19 wrought and reset economic growth onto a higher and more sustainable path. How powerful is the plan? S&P Global Ratings estimates that Next Generation EU could add as much as 4.1% to GDP by 2026, according to our high-impact scenario. In a low-impact scenario, we believe the plan could add 1.5% to the EU's output by that time. Our scenario approach makes specific assumptions about these economic levers:

  • The multiplier effects of public spending,
  • The deployment of funds available,
  • The timing of the implementation of the plan, and
  • The absorption rates of EU funds in each country.

The two scenarios combine these levers differently to understand the potential impact of the EU fiscal stimulus on growth (see box 1 for details). Yet, we acknowledge the difficulties of estimating the economic impact in the five years ahead because of uncertainties about the plan's implementation. We assume the funds will be spent from mid-2021, though delays are likely.

image

In a low-impact scenario, we assume each country absorbs the plan's funds at the 51.4% EU-27 average rate for funds entitled under the last MFF (2014-2020). We set the multiplier effect at a conservative 1 and assume that only one-half of the grants scheduled for 2021 are affectively paid out, the rest in 2022. In this scenario, the cumulative effect on EU economic growth would be 1.5% of GDP in 2026, with strong differences across countries (see tables 1 and 2 in the appendix). The strongest impact on annual growth occurs in 2022, when the bulk of the funds should be spent, followed by a decreasing but positive boost to growth through 2026.

In a high-impact scenario, we adopt a resolutory more optimistic assumption about the absorption rate, considering that Next Generation EU grants do not have to be cofinanced and are expected to involve less red tape than past regular EU funds. We therefore set the absorption rate at 91.3% for the EU-27, the average for funds entitled over the previous MFF (2007-2013). The multiplier effect is 1.6 after four years, in line with our own estimations. We assume here as well that 50% of the grants scheduled for this year are effectively paid out, the rest in 2022. Under such assumptions, the cumulative effect on EU economic growth would be 4.1% of GDP in 2026, with even stronger differences among countries than under the low-impact scenario (see appendix).

Chart 1

image

Chart 2

image

Next Generation EU is in many ways supportive of European sovereign creditworthiness

All countries in the EU would benefit from the plan's direct effects on growth, though its power will mostly depend on the timing of disbursement, the absorption of EU funds, and the multiplier effects of public spending. Under our low-impact scenario, the level of GDP increases 1.5% above where it would have been without the Next Generation EU plan. At 1.3%, the eurozone figure is nearly identical. Under the high-impact scenario the gap remains equivalent, with GDP 4.1% higher after five years in the EU and the eurozone level 3.9% higher than in the absence of Next Generation EU. All member states see GDP increasing at least 0.2% under the low-impact scenario and 0.5% under the high-impact scenario. However, these estimates do not incorporate second-round effects of higher growth of individual economies through trade channels. Therefore, the results from this perspective, even under the high-impact scenario, may be conservative.

That said, not all countries may benefit equally. Indeed, Next Generation EU is designed to reduce the economic divides among EU national economies and accelerate the green and digital transition.

Another benefit would go beyond the individual EU member states, because of the way the plan will effectively be financed. Having the EU issue debt securities to finance the recovery plan, which is novel, could boost the international role of the euro as a green safe asset (See "The EU Recovery Plan Could Create Its Own Green Safe Asset," published on July 15, 2020) and help reduce the financial fragmentation of the public-sector bond market denominated in euros.

An additional economic benefit is related to each country's structural reform plans, which if fully implemented, would likely boost EU economic growth in the years to come. We view positively the conditionality of EU funds on these structural reforms because it strongly encourages governments to tackle key weaknesses that the crisis has exacerbated. By improving the business environment, the labor market, and education, among other factors, growth potential would increase. Economic growth is critical to reducing the current large budget deficits as well as government debt (in GDP terms) back to pre-pandemic levels and beyond. However, governments may shy away from implementing unpopular economic reforms. Any permanent economic dislocation related to the pandemic could cement opposition to labor and other market reforms--worsened by increased political fragmentation in many countries--with negative implications for growth and sovereign ratings.

Overall, we view the policy response at the EU level as supportive of European sovereigns' creditworthiness. That's because under the Next Generation plan, EU sovereigns have significant financial levers that can be deployed with substantial flexibility compared to traditional EU structural funds, which require cofinancing. However, as discussed above, the sheer volume of financial support available presents an absorption challenge. This suggests to us that the successful deployment of funds will require a reorganization of public administration to increase the speed, efficiency, and quality of spending.

Assumptions about the size of fiscal multipliers can lead to large forecasting gaps

While our assumptions for the first three economic levers can be taken from past observations or can be deduced rationally, the multiplier is a trickier but essential assumption. Underestimating the size of fiscal multipliers can lead to large forecasting errors, which was the case following the financial crisis (see Blanchard O. and Leigh D., "Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers," IMF, WP/131). There is no clear consensus about the size of multipliers for the European economy. Because fiscal stimulus and growth are linked, econometrics offers only limited tools to isolate the impact they have on each other. Indeed, in many simulations of the impact of fiscal stimulus, fiscal multipliers are considered merely as endogenous variables (subject to influence by other variables inside the scope of analysis). What's more, the academic literature on fiscal multipliers has found that the impact of a fiscal stimulus on growth varies according to the context in which the economy evolves, which reduces the data sample available to estimate such effects.

For these reasons, we compute the fiscal multiplier for the European economy using state-of-the-art estimation methods that isolate the size of the fiscal multiplier depending on the state of the economy and its monetary policy stance (for the methodology see "The Case For Bold Fiscal Stimulus In The Eurozone," Nov. 17, 2020). Our economic modeling suggests fiscal stimulus has the highest impact on growth when demand is depressed and interest rates are negative, which is the current state of the European economy. In the current context, both fiscal and monetary policy are aimed at getting the economy back on track. As there is a lot of slack in the economy, fiscal stimulus is unlikely to feed into high import spillovers or trigger inflationary pressures and therefore, monetary policy is likely to remain supportive, enabling governments, firms, and consumers to finance their investments at low costs, in response to the demand created by the fiscal expansion. According to our estimates, the Next Generation EU stimulus could boost growth between 1.6 and 2 times the amount spent after four years in the eurozone, that is, for every €100 spent, economies would generate up to €200 (see chart 3).

Chart 3

image

The full deployment of funds is subject to conditions that would foster the green and the digital transition

In our simulation, we assume the European Commission validates the full amount of spending plans submitted by the member states. For countries to receive the full amount of grants to which they are entitled, the national recovery plans need to meet the conditions agreed by EU member states in July 2020. Notably, the RRF, which represents with €338 billion the bulk of grants under Next Generation EU, clearly prioritizes the green and digital transitions: Each national plan needs to include a minimum 37% of spending on climate investment and reforms and 20% to foster the digital transition. The plans will be assessed by the European Commission against these criteria and might see their allocations reduced in case they are not met. A clearer view in this regard will be possible after all countries submit their draft plans to the European Commission by the end of April. A look at the draft plans that were submitted well in advance shows important divergences among member countries. The German and French plans, most of which are financed with the countries' own resources, overshoot the targets for the green and digital criteria. The Spanish government is planning to spend 37% of its funds on green priorities and 33% on digitization. However, it seems less clear for the time being whether all countries' plans will meet these requirements. Consequently, there is a possibility that some countries will not be eligible for the full allocations of funds.

Delays in spending are likely, with differences by country

We assume the funds will be spent from mid-2021, though delays are likely. This is because the EU may take more time than expected to disburse the funds and because the approval of projects to finance might take some time in countries less able to frontload spending ahead of receiving the EU grants. However, such delays would affect the timing of spending, reducing spending in 2021 to the benefit of 2022, and therefore constitute a postponement rather than a loss in GDP growth.

It is important to note that EU countries do not have to wait for the EU money to start spending in line with their fiscal recovery plans. Indeed, most sovereigns have been prefinancing spending, at the national level, that they expect to reimburse with EU inflows. As a result, they already started spending last year to kickstart economic recovery. Indeed, the EU will accept projects that started in 2020 as long as they fall under the recovery plan submitted and approved by the EU. This means that even for net beneficiaries of the EU stimulus, countries just have to prefinance the stimulus themselves, which doesn't come at excessive cost given currently low interest rates.

The extent and speed at which countries absorb funds are other crucial determinants of the economic impact

Member states may not be able to absorb the EU funds in full. On average, all EU funds (cohesion funds, European Regional Development Fund, European Social Fund) entitled under the last MFF were absorbed at an average 51.4% after seven years, though widely varying by country, ranging from 38% for Austria to 66% for Greece (see chart 4). Past absorption rates of EU funds may prove a bit misleading this time, given the different nature of the recovery plan (no cofinancing and less red tape, for example) and the fact that all economies are running below their potential and so have more space to absorb stimulus.

Chart 4

image

Appendix: S&P Global Ratings' estimates of growth impact by country

Tables 1 and 2 show the marginal economic effect of the Next Generation EU plan on each 27 member states' GDP, that is the increase arising from the plan over the baseline. We present the results on annual basis on one side and on a cumulative basis (that is, compared with 2020 GDP) on the other side.

Table 1

S&P Global Ratings’ Low-Impact GDP Growth Scenario For The Next Generation EU Plan
Assumptions: Absorption rate = the average for total EU funds 2014-2020; multiplier = 1; full allotment of entitled grants; one-half of grants due in 2021 are postponed to 2022
Implied annual GDP growth Cumulative GDP growth (compared to 2020 GDP=100)
2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Belgium 0.1 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.4 100.4 100.5 100.5 100.6
Bulgaria 1.1 3.0 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 100.0 101.1 104.1 104.6 105.1 105.6 106.1
Czech Republic 0.5 1.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 100.0 100.5 101.7 101.9 102.1 102.3 102.5
Denmark 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.2 100.2 100.3 100.3 100.3
Germany 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.3 100.3 100.3 100.4 100.4
Estonia 0.7 1.7 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.7 102.4 102.7 103.0 103.3 103.6
Ireland 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.0 100.2 100.2 100.2 100.2 100.2
Greece 1.6 4.2 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.5 100.0 101.6 105.9 106.5 107.1 107.7 108.3
Spain 0.6 1.5 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 100.0 100.6 102.2 102.4 102.5 102.7 102.9
France 0.2 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.2 100.7 100.7 100.8 100.9 100.9
Croatia 1.2 3.0 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 100.0 101.2 104.2 104.6 105.0 105.4 105.8
Italy 0.4 1.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.4 101.4 101.5 101.7 101.8 101.9
Cyprus 0.6 1.6 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 100.0 100.6 102.3 102.5 102.8 103.0 103.3
Latvia 0.9 2.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.9 103.3 103.6 103.9 104.3 104.6
Lithuania 0.7 1.9 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.7 102.6 102.9 103.2 103.4 103.7
Luxemburg 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.2 100.2 100.2 100.2 100.2
Hungary 0.8 2.1 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.8 102.9 103.2 103.4 103.7 104.0
Malta 0.4 0.8 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.4 101.3 101.4 101.4 101.5 101.6
Netherlands 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.3 100.3 100.3 100.4 100.4
Austria 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.3 100.3 100.4 100.4 100.4
Poland 0.6 1.7 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.6 102.4 102.6 102.9 103.2 103.5
Portugal 0.9 2.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.9 103.3 103.6 103.9 104.2 104.5
Romania 0.7 1.8 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 100.0 100.7 102.5 102.7 103.0 103.3 103.5
Slovenia 0.6 1.4 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 100.0 100.6 101.9 102.1 102.3 102.5 102.7
Slovakia 0.7 1.7 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 100.0 100.7 102.4 102.7 102.9 103.1 103.4
Finland 0.1 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.1 100.5 100.6 100.6 100.7 100.7
Sweden 0.1 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.3 100.4 100.4 100.4 100.5
EU-27 0.3 0.8 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.3 101.1 101.2 101.3 101.4 101.5
Eurozone 0.3 0.7 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.3 100.9 101.0 101.1 101.2 101.3
Source: S&P Global Ratings.

Table 2

S&P Global Ratings’ High-Impact GDP Growth Scenario For The Next Generation EU Plan
Assumptions: Absorption rate = The average for total EU funds 2007-2013; multiplier = 1.6 after four years (linear progression); full allotment of entitled grants; one-half of grants due in 2021 are postponed to 2022
Implied annual GDP growth Cumulative GDP growth (compared to 2020 GDP=100)
2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Belgium 0.5 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 100.0 100.2 101.0 101.3 101.6 101.9 102.0
Bulgaria 4.4 4.5 2.4 2.5 1.9 1.4 100.0 102.2 108.6 111.2 114.1 116.6 118.2
Czech Republic 1.5 1.5 0.8 0.9 0.7 0.5 100.0 100.8 102.9 103.7 104.7 105.5 106.0
Denmark 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.1 100.4 100.6 100.7 100.8 100.9
Germany 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.2 100.6 100.8 101.0 101.2 101.3
Estonia 2.1 2.0 1.1 1.2 0.9 0.7 100.0 101.1 103.9 105.1 106.3 107.5 108.2
Ireland 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.3 100.3 100.4 100.5 100.5
Greece 4.8 4.6 2.4 2.5 1.7 1.2 100.0 102.4 109.1 111.7 114.5 116.9 118.3
Spain 2.9 2.5 1.3 1.4 0.9 0.6 100.0 101.4 105.2 106.6 108.1 109.4 110.1
France 0.7 0.7 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.2 100.0 100.4 101.4 101.8 102.2 102.6 102.8
Croatia 4.3 4.2 2.1 2.2 1.5 1.0 100.0 102.1 108.2 110.5 113.0 115.1 116.3
Italy 1.9 1.6 0.9 0.9 0.6 0.4 100.0 100.9 103.4 104.3 105.2 106.1 106.5
Cyprus 2.1 2.0 1.1 1.2 0.8 0.6 100.0 101.1 104.0 105.1 106.4 107.4 108.1
Latvia 3.1 3.1 1.6 1.7 1.2 0.8 100.0 101.5 105.9 107.6 109.4 111.0 112.0
Lithuania 2.2 2.2 1.2 1.2 0.9 0.6 100.0 101.1 104.2 105.5 106.7 107.9 108.5
Luxemburg 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 100.0 100.1 100.4 100.4 100.5 100.6 100.6
Hungary 2.4 2.3 1.2 1.2 0.9 0.6 100.0 101.2 104.5 105.7 107.0 108.1 108.8
Malta 1.5 1.1 0.6 0.7 0.4 0.3 100.0 100.8 102.5 103.1 103.8 104.3 104.6
Netherlands 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.1 100.6 100.7 100.9 101.1 101.2
Austria 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 100.0 100.2 100.8 101.0 101.2 101.4 101.5
Poland 2.0 2.1 1.1 1.2 0.9 0.6 100.0 101.0 103.9 105.1 106.4 107.5 108.2
Portugal 3.0 2.8 1.5 1.5 1.0 0.7 100.0 101.5 105.6 107.1 108.7 110.2 110.9
Romania 2.5 2.6 1.4 1.5 1.1 0.7 100.0 101.3 104.9 106.4 107.9 109.3 110.1
Slovenia 1.9 1.8 1.0 1.0 0.7 0.5 100.0 101.0 103.6 104.6 105.7 106.6 107.2
Slovakia 2.8 2.8 1.5 1.5 1.1 0.8 100.0 101.4 105.4 107.0 108.6 110.1 110.9
Finland 0.4 0.5 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.1 100.0 100.2 100.8 101.1 101.3 101.6 101.7
Sweden 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 100.0 100.2 100.6 100.8 100.9 101.1 101.2
EU-27 1.1 1.0 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.3 100.0 100.6 102.0 102.6 103.2 103.8 104.1
Eurozone 1.1 1.0 0.5 0.6 0.4 0.3 100.0 100.5 102.0 102.5 103.1 103.6 103.9
Source: S&P Global Ratings.

Editor: Rose Marie Burke. Digital Designer: Tom Lowenstein.

This report does not constitute a rating action.

EMEA Chief Economist:Sylvain Broyer, Frankfurt + 49 693 399 9156;
sylvain.broyer@spglobal.com
Senior Economist:Marion Amiot, London + 44(0)2071760128;
marion.amiot@spglobal.com
Economist:Sarah Limbach, Paris + 33 14 420 6708;
Sarah.Limbach@spglobal.com
Primary Credit Analysts:Frank Gill, Madrid + 34 91 788 7213;
frank.gill@spglobal.com
Marko Mrsnik, Madrid + 34 91 389 6953;
marko.mrsnik@spglobal.com

No content (including ratings, credit-related analyses and data, valuations, model, software or other application or output therefrom) or any part thereof (Content) may be modified, reverse engineered, reproduced or distributed in any form by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written permission of Standard & Poor’s Financial Services LLC or its affiliates (collectively, S&P). The Content shall not be used for any unlawful or unauthorized purposes. S&P and any third-party providers, as well as their directors, officers, shareholders, employees or agents (collectively S&P Parties) do not guarantee the accuracy, completeness, timeliness or availability of the Content. S&P Parties are not responsible for any errors or omissions (negligent or otherwise), regardless of the cause, for the results obtained from the use of the Content, or for the security or maintenance of any data input by the user. The Content is provided on an “as is” basis. S&P PARTIES DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING, BUT NOT LIMITED TO, ANY WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE OR USE, FREEDOM FROM BUGS, SOFTWARE ERRORS OR DEFECTS, THAT THE CONTENT’S FUNCTIONING WILL BE UNINTERRUPTED OR THAT THE CONTENT WILL OPERATE WITH ANY SOFTWARE OR HARDWARE CONFIGURATION. In no event shall S&P Parties be liable to any party for any direct, indirect, incidental, exemplary, compensatory, punitive, special or consequential damages, costs, expenses, legal fees, or losses (including, without limitation, lost income or lost profits and opportunity costs or losses caused by negligence) in connection with any use of the Content even if advised of the possibility of such damages.

Credit-related and other analyses, including ratings, and statements in the Content are statements of opinion as of the date they are expressed and not statements of fact. S&P’s opinions, analyses and rating acknowledgment decisions (described below) are not recommendations to purchase, hold, or sell any securities or to make any investment decisions, and do not address the suitability of any security. S&P assumes no obligation to update the Content following publication in any form or format. The Content should not be relied on and is not a substitute for the skill, judgment and experience of the user, its management, employees, advisors and/or clients when making investment and other business decisions. S&P does not act as a fiduciary or an investment advisor except where registered as such. While S&P has obtained information from sources it believes to be reliable, S&P does not perform an audit and undertakes no duty of due diligence or independent verification of any information it receives. Rating-related publications may be published for a variety of reasons that are not necessarily dependent on action by rating committees, including, but not limited to, the publication of a periodic update on a credit rating and related analyses.

To the extent that regulatory authorities allow a rating agency to acknowledge in one jurisdiction a rating issued in another jurisdiction for certain regulatory purposes, S&P reserves the right to assign, withdraw or suspend such acknowledgment at any time and in its sole discretion. S&P Parties disclaim any duty whatsoever arising out of the assignment, withdrawal or suspension of an acknowledgment as well as any liability for any damage alleged to have been suffered on account thereof.

S&P keeps certain activities of its business units separate from each other in order to preserve the independence and objectivity of their respective activities. As a result, certain business units of S&P may have information that is not available to other S&P business units. S&P has established policies and procedures to maintain the confidentiality of certain non-public information received in connection with each analytical process.

S&P may receive compensation for its ratings and certain analyses, normally from issuers or underwriters of securities or from obligors. S&P reserves the right to disseminate its opinions and analyses. S&P's public ratings and analyses are made available on its Web sites, www.standardandpoors.com (free of charge), and www.ratingsdirect.com and www.globalcreditportal.com (subscription), and may be distributed through other means, including via S&P publications and third-party redistributors. Additional information about our ratings fees is available at www.standardandpoors.com/usratingsfees.

Any Passwords/user IDs issued by S&P to users are single user-dedicated and may ONLY be used by the individual to whom they have been assigned. No sharing of passwords/user IDs and no simultaneous access via the same password/user ID is permitted. To reprint, translate, or use the data or information other than as provided herein, contact S&P Global Ratings, Client Services, 55 Water Street, New York, NY 10041; (1) 212-438-7280 or by e-mail to: research_request@spglobal.com.


 

Create a free account to unlock the article.

Gain access to exclusive research, events and more.

Already have an account?    Sign in