articles Ratings /ratings/en/research/articles/200520-economic-research-european-short-time-work-schemes-pave-the-way-for-a-smoother-recovery-11496298 content esgSubNav
In This List
COMMENTS

Economic Research: European Short-Time Work Schemes Pave The Way For A Smoother Recovery

COMMENTS

Economic Research: Global Economic Outlook Q1 2025: Buckle Up

COMMENTS

Economic Outlook U.S. Q1 2025: Steady Growth, Significant Policy Uncertainty

COMMENTS

Economic Outlook Emerging Markets Q1 2025: Trade Uncertainty Threatens Growth

COMMENTS

Economic Outlook Canada Q1 2025: Immigration Policies Hamper Growth Expectations


Economic Research: European Short-Time Work Schemes Pave The Way For A Smoother Recovery

The U.S. unemployment rate has soared in the past two months, but has risen only moderately in Europe. What accounts for the difference? S&P Global Ratings credits the contained increase in European unemployment to the use of extensive short-time work schemes in the region's largest economies, as an alternative to massive layoffs, as lockdowns constrain economic activity. While the U.S. unemployment rate rose 11 percentage points in just two months to stand at 14.7% in April, in the eurozone it rose by only 0.1 point in March to stand at 7.4%. Regional data coming from Spain and Ireland suggest another increase in April, while the claimant count in the U.K. points to a rise in the unemployment rate of less than 2.3 points in April.

Germany, followed by a few other countries, introduced short-time work during the last financial crisis. The OECD estimates that these schemes saved half a million jobs in the four largest EU economies during that time (see chart 1). However, the coronavirus pandemic marks a turning point in the use of short-time work. Initially designed to manage fluctuations in demand in certain sectors of activity such as industry or construction, short-time work has been extended to all employees in all sectors, with much looser eligibility criteria. This is linked to the non-economic origin of the shock. Lockdown policies in European countries are largely viewed as temporary measures to reduce the spread of COVID-19. Before the crisis, the economy was not suffering from major dislocations.

Chart 1

image

Chart 2

image

The high participation rate in short-time work already exceeds 27% of the labor force, far above 2% during the financial crisis. That's not only because it covers all sectors, but also because of the amplitude of the shock—about one-third of economic activity has been lost under lockdowns and because services, a more labor-intensive sector than industry, are particularly affected. As a result, despite a 7.3% contraction in GDP in the eurozone, we expect a relatively small rise in the unemployment rate to 8.5% in 2020, only 1.1 points above its level before the pandemic (see "Europe Braces for a Deeper Recession In 2020," published on April 20, 2020).

Short-time work schemes will support household income and consumption

In addition to saving jobs, short-time work schemes also help limit the drop in workers' incomes compared to unemployment benefits (see chart 3). In this way, they are more effective at supporting the liquidity of households, by helping them to meet obligations like mortgage payments. In a second stage, this will boost consumption when lockdowns are relaxed.

Short-time work also provides more job security, suggesting that consumers would less likely increase their precautionary savings during a crisis. As such, short-time income is likely to be higher than unemployment benefits as short-time workers obtain a full wage for the hours worked in their job. Meanwhile, the compensation for hours not worked under the state scheme is roughly equal to unemployment benefits in Spain, Italy, and Germany. In France, and most notably in the U.K., compensation for reduced hours is higher than unemployment benefits.

Chart 3

image

Short-time work schemes are likely less costly for governments

The cost of short-time work schemes in terms of public finances appears to be very high--€100 billion or more for the five largest European economies, but the cost would likely have been even higher if workers had been unemployed instead. As employees do work some hours under short-time work, the cost of reduced economic activity is shared between companies and the state. The greater the number of working hours maintained, the lower the fiscal cost compared with unemployment benefits. In Germany, Italy, and Spain, benefits for hours not worked are equal to unemployment benefits (see table). Thus, the cost of short-time work does not exceed the cost of a situation where workers would have received unemployment benefits.

Table 1

Short-Time Work Schemes Compared To Unemployment Benefits For Selected European Countries
Unemployment benefits Short-time Work Scheme Benefits
Germany 60% or 67% of the net wage depending on familial situation. Maximal allocation set at €2,805 for new landers and €2,625 for old landers. 60% of the missing net wage or 67% if the worker is parent. Allowance provided for monthly wages that do not exceed €6,500 in western Germany and €5,800 in eastern germany
France 57% of the reference daily wage (SJR) or 40.4%+12€ within the limit of 75% of the SJR. Maximum allowance set at €253 per day 84% of the missing net wage with maximal allocation set a €31.97 per hour
Spain 70% of the reference salary for the first 180 days and 50% from the 7th month. Maximal allocation set between €1,098 and €1,411 depending on familial situation 70% of the missing net wage. This allowance is capped at €1,098/month or €1,411 depending on familial situation
Italy 75% of the net wage, decreasing by 3% each month after the 4th month. Maximal allocation set at €1,328 80% of the missing net wage with maximal allocation set at €998 when the reference salary is lower €2,159 or €1,199 when the reference salary is higher than €2,159
U.K. Lump sum, depending on the age of the person concerned: €65.80/week for a person under 25 years old and €83/week for a person over 25 years of age 80% of the net reference salary with a maximal allocation set at €2,500
Sources: Unedic, national ministries of labor.

The trade-off is less clear cut in France and especially in the U.K. In France, hours not worked are compensated at a higher rate than unemployment benefits (84% against slightly more than 57% depending on the wage, see table). Still, for the cost of the scheme to exceed the cost of unemployment benefits, short-time workers would have to work on average less than 30% their normal hours. Meanwhile, the U.K. furlough scheme is more expensive, as it does not allow for reduced working time and is much more generous than unemployment benefits.

However, short-time workers are expected to return to work relatively quickly after lockdowns, while the unemployed are likely to remain without work for a longer period because job creation takes time (see chart 4).

Chart 4

image

Thus, even if short-time work schemes may cost more in the short term, costs are likely lower in the medium and longer term. This policy lays the foundations for a quicker recovery by keeping the link between employees and employers. Workers are not at risk of losing their skills, and both sides do not have to undergo a costly rematching process. This enhances the overall effect of the scheme while compensating for the higher short-term direct costs of the short-time work scheme for France and the U.K.

The efficiency of short-time work decreases as the economy recovers and for lower-skilled jobs

Although it is clear that large-scale use of short-time work is preventing a sharp rise in unemployment in Europe, it will become more costly and less relevant as activity picks up. When the economy recovers, firms will be increasingly able to retain viable jobs without public support, and the cost of retaining uncompetitive jobs will rise.

For sectors that will see a normal resumption of activity as lockdowns are loosened, short-time work schemes are likely to be gradually phased out. That said, the gradual loosening of lockdowns and the need for social-distancing measures suggest that some sectors such as transport, hospitality, and leisure will suffer from a slower recovery. Thus, a major challenge will be to maintain a system for safeguarding employment that does not hinder the reallocation of work to growth sectors. That's when conditional requirements will be more important. For example, during the financial crisis, some countries prohibited dismissals during or after the duration of short-time work, asked for a recovery plan, or demanded workers look for a job or get retrained during nonworking hours. Those measures reduced the chance that short-time work schemes kept jobs alive that were not viable without the subsidy.

Chart 5

image

Workers in the tourism sector will probably suffer the most from an early end to short-time work schemes, given that it will take many months before the sector can return to prepandemic levels of activity.

In view of the upturn in economic activity that has begun in recent days, some countries will certainly adjust their systems by limiting the number of subsidized hours of unemployment or by reducing the number of hours covered. The French government has announced that it will continue to subsidize jobs for companies closed by administrative decision. If the scheme were to disappear too soon, the rise in unemployment would be significant, as tourism employment comprises about 8% of total employment and about 9% of enterprises in the largest European economies (see chart 6). Even in Germany, tourism accounts for 3.9% of total gross value added, ahead of machinery and equipment manufacturing, retail, and financial services (according to Germany's Federal Ministry of Tourism Affairs).

Chart 6

image

Meanwhile, compared with permanent workers, freelance and temporary workers are much less likely to benefit from short-time work. It is also more likely they will lose their jobs in a downturn as hiring and firing costs tend to be lower for workers in temporary jobs. Spain is the most exposed to this risk, with the highest share of temporary contracts (see chart 7). Therefore, we expect that country to see a larger rise in unemployment despite its short-time work scheme.

Chart 7

image

It is also likely, as in the last recession, that many of the jobs retained by the scheme will be lost when it's phased out. The rate of conversion into unemployment is typically much higher than for other workers: In France after the financial crisis, a short-time worker was twice as likely to become unemployed than a worker not covered by the scheme, according to Dares Analyses (January 2012, No. 004). However, it is not clear how high this rate will be during this downturn, as it will depend on the duration of the scheme, access to credit for small and midsize enterprises, and how and when activity recovers (in France, 57% of requests for reduced working hours come from firms with fewer than 50 employees and limited access to credit, see chart 8).

Chart 8

image

The longer lockdowns last, the more likely it is in any case that firms lay off their workers, as there exist many kinds of financial burdens for closed businesses during lockdowns. According to the business impact of the coronavirus according to a U.K. survey (BICS, released on April 23), only 60% of businesses were confident they had sufficient financial resources available to survive the economic fallout from the pandemic.

This report does not constitute a rating action.

Senior Economist:Marion Amiot, London + 44 20 7176 0128;
marion.amiot@spglobal.com
Economics Intern:William Elsayed, London;
william.el.sayed@spglobal.com
EMEA Chief Economist:Sylvain Broyer, Frankfurt (49) 69-33-999-156;
sylvain.broyer@spglobal.com

No content (including ratings, credit-related analyses and data, valuations, model, software or other application or output therefrom) or any part thereof (Content) may be modified, reverse engineered, reproduced or distributed in any form by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written permission of Standard & Poor’s Financial Services LLC or its affiliates (collectively, S&P). The Content shall not be used for any unlawful or unauthorized purposes. S&P and any third-party providers, as well as their directors, officers, shareholders, employees or agents (collectively S&P Parties) do not guarantee the accuracy, completeness, timeliness or availability of the Content. S&P Parties are not responsible for any errors or omissions (negligent or otherwise), regardless of the cause, for the results obtained from the use of the Content, or for the security or maintenance of any data input by the user. The Content is provided on an “as is” basis. S&P PARTIES DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING, BUT NOT LIMITED TO, ANY WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE OR USE, FREEDOM FROM BUGS, SOFTWARE ERRORS OR DEFECTS, THAT THE CONTENT’S FUNCTIONING WILL BE UNINTERRUPTED OR THAT THE CONTENT WILL OPERATE WITH ANY SOFTWARE OR HARDWARE CONFIGURATION. In no event shall S&P Parties be liable to any party for any direct, indirect, incidental, exemplary, compensatory, punitive, special or consequential damages, costs, expenses, legal fees, or losses (including, without limitation, lost income or lost profits and opportunity costs or losses caused by negligence) in connection with any use of the Content even if advised of the possibility of such damages.

Credit-related and other analyses, including ratings, and statements in the Content are statements of opinion as of the date they are expressed and not statements of fact. S&P’s opinions, analyses and rating acknowledgment decisions (described below) are not recommendations to purchase, hold, or sell any securities or to make any investment decisions, and do not address the suitability of any security. S&P assumes no obligation to update the Content following publication in any form or format. The Content should not be relied on and is not a substitute for the skill, judgment and experience of the user, its management, employees, advisors and/or clients when making investment and other business decisions. S&P does not act as a fiduciary or an investment advisor except where registered as such. While S&P has obtained information from sources it believes to be reliable, S&P does not perform an audit and undertakes no duty of due diligence or independent verification of any information it receives. Rating-related publications may be published for a variety of reasons that are not necessarily dependent on action by rating committees, including, but not limited to, the publication of a periodic update on a credit rating and related analyses.

To the extent that regulatory authorities allow a rating agency to acknowledge in one jurisdiction a rating issued in another jurisdiction for certain regulatory purposes, S&P reserves the right to assign, withdraw or suspend such acknowledgment at any time and in its sole discretion. S&P Parties disclaim any duty whatsoever arising out of the assignment, withdrawal or suspension of an acknowledgment as well as any liability for any damage alleged to have been suffered on account thereof.

S&P keeps certain activities of its business units separate from each other in order to preserve the independence and objectivity of their respective activities. As a result, certain business units of S&P may have information that is not available to other S&P business units. S&P has established policies and procedures to maintain the confidentiality of certain non-public information received in connection with each analytical process.

S&P may receive compensation for its ratings and certain analyses, normally from issuers or underwriters of securities or from obligors. S&P reserves the right to disseminate its opinions and analyses. S&P's public ratings and analyses are made available on its Web sites, www.standardandpoors.com (free of charge), and www.ratingsdirect.com and www.globalcreditportal.com (subscription), and may be distributed through other means, including via S&P publications and third-party redistributors. Additional information about our ratings fees is available at www.standardandpoors.com/usratingsfees.

Any Passwords/user IDs issued by S&P to users are single user-dedicated and may ONLY be used by the individual to whom they have been assigned. No sharing of passwords/user IDs and no simultaneous access via the same password/user ID is permitted. To reprint, translate, or use the data or information other than as provided herein, contact S&P Global Ratings, Client Services, 55 Water Street, New York, NY 10041; (1) 212-438-7280 or by e-mail to: research_request@spglobal.com.

 

Create a free account to unlock the article.

Gain access to exclusive research, events and more.

Already have an account?    Sign in